Advertisement

Visible Inflation, Not Invisible Recession, Is No. 1 Enemy

Share
<i> Robert J. Samuelson writes about economic issues from Washington</i>

It’s hard to envy Alan Greenspan, the new chairman of the Federal Reserve Board. The Fed regulates interest rates, but, in the wake of the stock market crash, dangers lurk no matter how Greenspan moves rates. Higher rates could trigger an economic slowdown or recession. Lower rates could cause a dangerous collapse of the dollar and higher inflation. All that Greenspan can do is make an educated guess and guard against the greatest danger. At the moment, that’s visible inflation--not an invisible recession.

Just how he reacts will help shape the world economy. In the weeks since the market crash, the global dimensions of the economic impasse have become increasingly clear. For the first half of the 1980s, the world grew in an unstable way. The United States’ huge appetite for imports propelled other economies. The immense U.S. trade deficit corresponded to the enormous trade surpluses of West Germany, Japan, Taiwan and other countries. The question now is whether this lopsided pattern of global growth can be gracefully reversed.

In some ways Greenspan was one of the big winners of the stock market crash. It enabled him to escape quickly from the shadow of his predecessor, Paul Volcker. No one ever doubted either Greenspan’s intelligence or his credentials as an economist. But crisis management is an art, not a science, and everyone wondered whether Greenspan had the needed instincts and skills. For the moment, he has quieted the critics.

Advertisement

When the market dropped sharply, Greenspan acted decisively. The Fed made added credit available to banks, which could lend to hard-pressed brokers or mutual funds, thereby preventing the financial panic from feeding on itself. For all its impressiveness, though, this performance still leaves unanswered the question of how Greenspan will handle the broader problems of inflation and recession.

His position is anomalous. Lower interest rates are the traditional medicine for an economic slowdown. Indeed, the Fed cut a key interest rate after the crash as a means of providing short-term emergency credit. Greenspan’s dilemma is that he can’t go much further down this path--maybe he has already gone too far--without creating as many problems as he solves.

All evidence points to continuing U.S. prosperity. There is already something of a mini- boom in exports. In the third quarter the gross national product grew at a brisk 4.1% annual rate. Of course the stock market crash could change the outlook. Overburdened by debt and alarmed by the crash, consumers may delay spending. But, unless the effect is dramatic, lower interest rates risk overheating the economy and worsening inflation.

The country’s unemployment rate now stands at only 6%. Factory utilization is rising sharply. The economy can’t tolerate both an export boom and strong domestic spending without fostering inflationary pressures. All inflation indexes are rising faster than in 1986, and only part of the increase reflects the erratic swings in oil prices. Corporate purchasing agents report lengthening delivery times for new goods. A lower dollar is raising import prices.

A belief that the United States will tolerate higher inflation could also become self-fulfilling by triggering a collapse of the dollar. Inflation fears would prompt investors to dump the dollar, and higher import prices would intensify inflation. The dollar is fated to depreciate, but it matters whether the drop is gradual or sudden. A slow decline would allow American exporters to expand production capacity while other countries try to speed up their economies. Foreign exporters can shift production to the United States and ease the risk of domestic scarcities.

But none of these changes can occur instantly. The inescapable conclusion is that Greenspan and the Fed should continue to resist inflation--not because it is a risk-free policy but because the alternatives are worse. The inflationary effect of a sharp drop in the dollar would either lead to a permanent rise of inflation or, more likely, force the Fed to subdue inflation by causing a slump. Meanwhile, the dramatic loss of exports to the U.S. market could drive foreign economies into recession.

Advertisement

Whatever gamble Greenspan takes, he must contend not only with economic uncertainties but also with the pressures of public opinion. Here a comparison with the crash of 1929 is apt. There was a lot of talk then about the economy’s fundamental strength and the crash’s therapeutic effects. It would punish speculators and reassert the value of work. In 1987 this sort of moralizing has been minimal. The almost-universal response has been: Oh, my gosh, we can’t let this lead to a recession.

The contrast is worth pondering. With hindsight, the 1929 reaction rationalized government passivity that contributed to the onset of the Great Depression. But today’s reaction poses the opposite danger. The eagerness to avoid recession, even if it initially succeeds, could lead to more serious economic problems later.

Advertisement