Advertisement

Paul Carpenter’s Conviction Takes Us Beyond ‘Smoking Gun’ Corruption : Politics: Selling access can be as unacceptable as selling votes, the jury said. But comprehensive campaign reform is still needed.

Share
<i> Walter A. Zelman writes about California government and politics. </i>

For many years, legislators, lobbyists and major campaign contributors have defended California’s system of financing political campaigns by arguing that contributions do not buy votes--only increase access to those who cast them. While the system, the defenders concede, may offer some advantages to major contributors, those advantages--merely the better chance to make one’s case--are not the stuff of which political corruption is made.

This defense has always been weak, if not wholly specious. Even if its premise--that contributions only buy increased access--were granted, the line separating access and outright influence has always been thin. In politics, access is power.

As legislative deadlines approach, for example, lobbyists line up outside legislative chambers in the hope of getting 10 minutes with the overwhelmed legislators. They hand their business cards to the pages, who carry the notes onto the floor. There, the legislators decide who they will see and who will get the “Sorry, it’s just too busy now” response. Even when there’s no hint of an “I contributed--now you vote” arrangement, the ability to get two minutes to “explain” your position on this or that bill is real power.

Advertisement

For these reasons, the recent conviction of former state Sen. Paul B. Carpenter--the second guilty verdict growing out of the FBI’s Sacramento sting operation--sends some precedent-setting signals. By convicting Carpenter of selling access--as opposed to just votes--the jury was drawing new lines in the political sand, defining as unacceptable what many may have once considered acceptable. At minimum, the jurors were suggesting that elected officials must take greater care not to favor--even in terms of personal availability--contributors over non-contributors.

Even if such a warning becomes more an ethical standard than an enforceable law, the Carpenter conviction may serve to focus media and public attention on some of the most pervasive, if less visible, forms of political corruption.

Most corruption stories zero in on the search for a “smoking gun”--lobbyist gives legislator $5,000 in exchange for legislator’s vote. But most examples of political corruption take far more subtle, but no less dangerous, forms than the smoking-gun analogy suggests. They involve the constant bending of ethical boundaries by large numbers rather than the unquestioned crossing of the lines by small numbers.

As a result, it is wiser--and, in terms of prevention, more profitable--to envision political corruption as a systemic disease capable of undercutting the rules of the political game rather than as a psychological disease infecting only individual players. What a political system will not long survive are widespread pressures that encourage large numbers of reasonably honorable players to undertake dishonorable activities. Put another way, a system may be able to withstand a few individuals occasionally selling access. It will not long withstand many individuals selling access.

Such widespread unethical activity does more than undermine the public standing of government institutions. It frequently renders them powerless to address and resolve critical public policy issues. Most pressure on elected officials comes from special interests protecting special needs. Too much pressure from too many interests results in political stalemate. As founding Common Cause Chairman John Gardner said, the decision-making playing field comes to resemble a board of checkers, with each special interest placing a thumb on, and immobilizing, one checker. Ultimately, all the checkers are covered.

For some years now, California’s political process has been at just such a breaking point. There have been too many pressures on too many legislators to cross ethical boundary lines too often. Government has continued to grow in scope and power, increasing the numbers of organized entities with greater need and will to influence the process. Campaign costs have skyrocketed, creating a dangerous but almost unavoidable attraction between the financial needs of elected officials and the designs of private interests.

Advertisement

To its credit, the Legislature has made some effort to reduce these pressures. Last year, it placed on the ballot a constitutional amendment, approved in June, that, among other things, bans honoraria, closes the “revolving door” between public and private service and tightens conflict-of-interest rules.

But the Legislature, as a whole, has consistently rejected the most critical reform, that most directly addresses the systemic nature of political corruption. California’s campaign-finance system continues to force virtually all candidates--even the most honorable--to stretch the ethical margins to the breaking point. The endless search for special-interest contributions often poses a play-the-game-or-lose scenario for candidates, and that choice can be hard.

The 1988 enactment of Proposition 73, a poorly conceived initiative, only aggravated the problem. Although its limits on campaign contributions may be held unconstitutional, its provision banning public financing of campaigns remains in force. Thus, an increasingly accepted means of providing qualified candidates with string-free campaign funds has thus been eliminated. Comprehensive campaign-finance reform--including contribution and spending limits, as well as a system of public financing--remains the giant, missing piece in California ethics reform.

Most reforms aimed at heightening ethical standards--like those recently enacted in California--have focused on legal sanctions for unethical behavior. But if corruption is really more a systemic than a psychological disease, medicines that ban specific activities will not be strong enough. Regardless of how many new political crimes we define, the attainment of higher ethics in government will remain a matter of example and public pressure. What is needed is a reduction (such as that provided by comprehensive campaign reform) of systemic incentives to perform unethically, and an increase in systemic incentives to perform ethically.

For this reason, elected officials, and others, might do well to consider offering more political and positive incentives as alternative means of inspiring and rewarding higher ethical standards. The new governor, for example, could send an powerful message by placing special emphasis on filling top administrative positions with individuals regarded as holding high ethical standards. The message--that political advancement and power were tied to compliance with superior ethical standards--would not have to be trumpeted.

Even the Carpenter conviction, with its suggestion that old ethical standards may now be against the law, should not obscure the reality that California’s current political crisis is much more one of ethics than law. Richard M. Nixon’s famous defense--”I am not a crook”--completely missed the mark, because legal standards fall far short of ethical standards. Unlike the law, which defines what one must do, ethics defines what one ought to do. Carpenter, and Sen. Joseph B. Montoya before him, did what one must not do. But things that ought not to be done are daily occurrences in California politics and, ultimately, should be the cause for much greater public concern.

Advertisement
Advertisement