Advertisement

CAPITAL POWER STRUGGLE : Don’t Bemoan Gridlock--the Constitution Likes It

Share
<i> James Q. Wilson is the Collins Professor of Management and Public Policy at UCLA and the author of "Bureaucracy" (Basic) and "The Moral Sense" (The Free Press)</i>

As we prepare for the convening of a new Congress, we ought to be clear about what we can expect. The defeat of health-care reform and the passage of the crime bill in the last Congress are widely misunderstood, in part because Democrats and Republicans are making partisan claims but in larger part because Americans do not understand what they can and cannot expect from their national government.

To liberal Democrats, Bill Clinton’s health-care plan was defeated because of political-action committee spending, Republican obstructionism, special-interest pressure and misleading television advertising. To conservative Republicans, the crime bill was passed because it was laden with “pork.”

The fate of high-profile political issues cannot solely be explained by personal failings, narrow partisanship or devious maneuvering. These forces are always at work, of course, and sometimes make a big difference, but whenever this country comes to grips with a major controversy, the way it is resolved usually depends more on the central features of the U.S. constitutional system than on the tactics of the participants. These features are:

Advertisement

* The system of checks and balances requires the creation of a majority coalition out of disparate, often antagonistic elements if any significant policy is to be adopted.

* In assembling such a coalition, the benefits of a program must appear to be real and the costs either small, deferred or displaced onto the “other guy.”

* If there is strong public demand for some specific federal action, coalitions can be formed out of the sheer pressure of electoral necessity; but if there is no such clear demand, members must receive side payments in exchange for joining the coalition.

* Despite the aggrandizement of federal power during the last half century, the Constitution and the political culture require that many policies be implemented by state and local authorities.

Applied to health care, these principles have the following implications:

A new policy initiative of the magnitude of Clinton’s health plan requires either a crisis or strong popular support if it is to pass. The plan must convince people that its benefits exceed its costs or that its costs will be paid by somebody else. The support of groups already delivering the service must be assured by making them part of the process and plan, or their opposition must be made ineffectual by isolating and demonizing them.

The Clinton health plan did not address some of these requirements and tried but failed to meet others. There was no popularly sensed “health-care crisis.” There was popular concern over rising health-care costs, but little demand for changing the ways in which the health-care needs of uninsured people are being met. The public thought the President gave an effective health-care speech to Congress, but few believed they were the people he was talking about. Groups now delivering health care--doctors, hospitals, insurance and pharmaceutical companies--were largely frozen out of policy development. Many large corporations like the idea of the government taking over some of their post-retirement health costs, but they were outnumbered by the small firms that resisted taking on new costs. The public wouldn’t mind seeing uninsured people receive care and their own coverage guaranteed, but they will only support these things if someone else pays. Clinton tried to persuade them that the “someone else” were greedy insurance and pharmaceutical companies and wasteful paper-shufflers, but his effort to demonize these groups failed.

Advertisement

Had the United States a parliamentary system, everything would have been different. In all likelihood, we would have long since had a single-payer system like Canada’s or some version of the German plan. But the U.S. Constitution does not permit us to move decisively in such directions without a crisis; it permits us, at best, to modify the existing system, correct the worst and most widely recognized problems and devise new ways of having public-private partnerships that take into account diverse local realities. So stop complaining about Harry and Louise ads, PAC spending and congressional gridlock.

Crime is a different story. There was, and is, in the public mind a genuine crisis, so some action is politically imperative. The problem is that neither the Constitution nor public opinion permits the federal government to do much except make symbolic gestures (the federal death penalty) and ship money to the states (to pay part of the costs of a few police officers, build some prisons and try some untested programs). And even to do these things, Washington must promise to help every congressional district and not just those with a severe crime problem. The recently announced allocation of federally subsidized police officers to the cities illustrates what this means--such crime hot spots as Stanislaus, Calif., St. Albans, Vt., and Rock Springs, Wyo., will get some “tree” cops.

In a parliamentary regime with political authority centralized in a national government, things would have been different. There would long since have been a national police force (or, as in England, a nationally funded and directed set of local police forces) enforcing a national criminal code. If the death penalty existed, it would be based on national law applicable to all offenders. There would probably still be a Bill of Rights of some sort, but there would be no strong, independent judiciary to enforce it against the legislative branch. Because parliamentary systems are more responsive to national elites than to local interests, penal policy would reflect, in large measure, the views of these elites (in much of Europe of late, those views have favored decarceration and rehabilitation). Would such a nationalized criminal-justice system produce less crime? Not if the recent experience of England, Germany and Sweden is any guide.

National elites influenced our crime bill as well, though not nearly to the same degree as would be the case abroad. The price of a largely meaningless expansion of the federal death penalty--and even more meaningless federal “three strikes” law--was the insertion of several billion dollars for untested social spending. Critics called this “pork,” as if that were a serious criticism.

But buying off potential coalition members with spending programs they favor is exactly what the Founders not only expected, but practiced. In 1790, Alexander Hamilton got his economic plan adopted in exchange for locating the capital district on the banks of the Potomac, as Thomas Jefferson wanted. Washington, D.C., was--literally--built on “pork.”

What is significant about pork today is not that it is less savory or more common, but that it has changed. Once pork meant tangible benefits to particular districts (such as a grant for Lamar College in the Texas congressional district of Rep. Jack Brooks); today, it increasingly means general rules and programs to satisfy nationally organized constituencies (such as programs that somebody believes prevent crime).

Advertisement

Many liberals and conservatives would like this country to have health and crime policies that are more “rational”--that is, systematically planned, carefully coordinated and centrally directed. Unless they want to scrap the Constitution, they should forget it. And a good thing, too; however messy, localistic and “irrational” our policies in these areas, they are likely to permit far greater levels of innovation and to be more easily subject to corrections in the light of experience than the “rational” policies abroad.*

Advertisement